Disassembly Required. Geoff Mann

Читать онлайн книгу.

Disassembly Required - Geoff Mann


Скачать книгу
down” to those who didn’t get the extra to begin with.

      In combination, these conceptual tools—rational pursuit of self-interest, clearing markets in which prices are determined by individual tastes, the invisible hand—form the core of modern “economic” knowledge, and its assertion that markets can make predictability, calculability, stability, and equilibrium possible.

      John Maynard Keynes

      From the early 1800s to World War II virtually all orthodox economists and “statesmen” in Europe and North America camped somewhere in the neo/classical range. The Great Depression that began in 1929, however, initiated a massive shift in what ideas were considered acceptable. So began the Keynesian era, named for the “revolutionary” work of the British economist John Maynard Keynes (1883–1946). We shouldn’t exaggerate the abruptness of the change. There were forerunners to Keynes’ ideas, and his took some time to become common sense. Classical/neoclassical ideas and policies persisted into and after the Depression. But there is no denying that between 1929 and the end of World War II, the world of political economy was transformed.

      When the Depression hit, Keynes (who had long defended this older thinking), saw that these ideas were just plain wrong: people wanted to hold money more than other stuff. They were buying less, investing less, and in general keeping the money and money-like things they had (things easy to use in exchange, like gold). And that, he said, should never ever happen if classical economics is right. Money was clearly not neutral, but had a very real, and fluctuating, value of its own as a security in the face of uncertainty. If money had ever been neutral in the classical sense (something he doubted), it was no longer. Modern capitalism, he said, is a “monetary production economy,” and money was perhaps its central institution, much more complex than a convenient means of payment and accounting device.

      Like most of his ideas, Keynes arrived at this conclusion via what he thought was simple common sense. Yes, he said, it is true that from a purely utility- or profit-maximizing perspective it makes more sense to use one’s cash holdings to consume and invest. But because the future is always uncertain, it makes sense, in the real world, to hold at least some money most of the time, and a lot of money at especially unstable times. Keynes called this propensity to hold assets in money form “liquidity preference,” “liquidity” being the ease with which an asset can be readily monetized, i.e., exchanged for money. So if “liquidity preference” is high, it suggests people feel insecure or uncertain, and do not want to be holding on to assets they will have trouble selling if things go south.

      Keynes argued that the state of liquidity preference among market participants, fluctuating in response to everything from weather to war, exercises enormous influence on modern monetary economies. The stock market, for example, enables rapid purchase and sale of highly liquid assets—indeed, the whole point of the stock market is to turn an enterprise, which on its own and as a whole is about as “illiquid” as it gets, into a collection of easily exchanged units of property. This is, of course, extremely useful and appealing to stock-holders, but difficult for the firms in question, whose bits and pieces are picked up and dropped in a flash—often for no apparent reason other than investors’ whims (a volatility only exacerbated in the “information age”). This is only one example of how prone capitalism is to what we might euphemistically call “inefficiencies.” It is one of a whole suite of dynamics that make the fundamental assumption of classical and neoclassical economic theory—that markets clear, resources are fully employed, and all engines are running full-bore—a highly improbable description of the world. Full employment, if it ever happens, will not hold for long. Keynes was pretty sure that, at least since the beginnings of capitalism, it had never happened.

      The older, Smith-Ricardo-Jevons traditions knew levels of activity could decrease, but they said that if prices, especially wages, decreased too, then firms would start producing, investing, and hiring again, workers would be pulled into jobs, and everything would be hunky-dory. But, Keynes said, look around at the capitalist world in which we actually live. Prices don’t adjust that easily: workers either resist wage cuts, or, more likely, even if they are willing to accept them, as many in the Depression were, they cannot coordinate any economy-wide reduction in labour costs anyway (it’s not like they have that power in capitalism). Investors won’t instantly become optimists and throw their capital into production and hiring. For any set of self-interested actors, there is a massive collective action problem. Often, he said, the only answer is for the state to step in as mediator, regulator, and coordinator of economic relationships: organizing labour and capital so as to manage consumer demand, planning investments so they are complementary, and providing stimulus in the form of government spending when consumers and investors start to feel insecure again, as they inevitably will.

      According to Keynes, this suboptimal up-and-down, occasionally with really high ups and really low downs, is how capitalism works. Its volatility is not a result of mismanagement or interference or workers’ demand for “excessive” wages, but a part of how it functions “naturally.” And, if the capitalist state does not manage the ups and downs, people might become so disgruntled that all that communism and socialism stuff whispered about in field and factory starts making sense. In the middle of the Depression and then World War II, with the Russian revolution in the background, that warning made many capitalists sit up and take notice. They may not have been big fans of liberal democracy, but it beat the alternative.

      More on this later (Chapter 5). But before we turn to the principle institutions of capitalism, it is worth noting that Keynesian ideas, in different forms (not all of which Keynes would have endorsed), dominated capitalist economic theorizing from World War II until the early 1970s. Explicitly Keynesian theory and policy fell with the rise of a reinvigorated, formally complex (“mathematical”), and strident form of neoclassical analysis that was the first step toward the capitalist ways of knowing and doing we live with today. The crisis that began in 2007 has certainly troubled this resurrected neoclassicism, but, despite their obvious flaws, there is no guarantee that neoclassical economics or the neoliberalism it underwrites will go the way of the dodo.