Alternative Investments. Hossein Kazemi

Читать онлайн книгу.

Alternative Investments - Hossein Kazemi


Скачать книгу
is the primary challenge that causes difficulty in calculating the return performance of a forward contract or another position that requires no net investment? How is that challenge addressed?

      3. Consider a position in a single forward contract. What distinguishes a fully collateralized position in this forward contract from a partially collateralized position?

      4. An IRR is estimated for a fund based on an initial investment when the fund was created, several annual distributions, and an estimate of the fund's value prior to its termination. What type of IRR is this?

      5. An investment has two solutions for its IRR. What can be said about the investment and the usefulness of the two solutions?

      6. Two investments are being compared to ascertain which would add the most value to a portfolio. Both investments have simplified cash flow patterns of an initial cost followed by positive cash flows. Why might the IRRs of the investments provide an unreliable indication of which would add more value?

      7. An analyst computes the IRR of one alternative to be 20 % and another to be 30 %. When the analyst combines the cash flows of the two alternatives into a single investment, must the IRR of the combination be greater than 20 % and less than 30 %?

      8. Is an IRR a dollar-weighted return or a time-weighted return? Why?

      9. In which scenario will a clawback clause lead to payments?

      10. What is the difference between a hard hurdle rate and a soft hurdle rate?

      CHAPTER 4

      Statistical Foundations

      This chapter provides foundational material regarding statistical methods for the study of alternative investments in general and for the subsequent material in this book in particular. The use of statistics in performing hypothesis tests is addressed in detail in Chapter 8.

      4.1 Return Distributions

      Risky assets experience unexpected value changes and therefore unexpected returns. If we assume that investors are rational, the more competitively traded an asset, the more these unexpected price changes may be random and unpredictable. Hence, asset prices and asset returns in competitively traded markets are typically modeled as random variables. Frequency and probability distributions therefore provide starting points for describing asset returns.

      4.1.1 Ex Ante and Ex Post Return Distributions

      Ex post returns are realized outcomes rather than anticipated outcomes. Future possible returns and their probabilities are referred to as expectational or ex ante returns. A crucial theme in understanding the analysis of alternative investments is to understand the differences and links between ex post and ex ante return data.

      Often, predictions are formed partially or fully through analysis of ex post data. For example, the ex ante or future return distribution of a stock index such as the S&P 500 Index is often assumed to be well approximated by the ex post or historical return distribution. The direct use of past return behavior as a predictor of future potential return behavior requires two properties to be accurate. First, the return distribution must be stationary through time, meaning that the expected return and the dispersion of the underlying asset do not change. Second, the sample of past observations must be sufficiently large to be likely to form a reasonably accurate representation of the process. For example, equity returns were very high during the bull market decade of the 1990s and very low during the early years of the financial crisis (2007–08). Using either of these time periods in isolation would likely overstate or understate the realistic long-run equity market returns.

      Taken together, the requirements for the past returns to be representative of the future returns raise a serious challenge. If the past observation period is long, the sample of historical returns will be large; however, it is likely that the oldest observations reflect different risks or other economic conditions than can be anticipated in the future. If the sample is limited to the most recent observations, the data may be more representative of future economic conditions, but the sample may be too small to draw accurate inferences from it.

      For a traditional asset, such as the common stock of a large, publicly traded corporation, it may be somewhat plausible that the asset's past behavior is a reasonable indication of its future behavior. However, many alternative investments are especially problematic in this context. For example, historical data may not exist for venture capital investment in new firms or may be difficult to observe or to obtain in cases such as private equity, where most or all trades are not publicly observable. Especially in alternative investments such as hedge funds, return distributions are expected to change as the fund's investment strategies and use of leverage change through time. In these cases and many others, ex ante return distributions may need to be based on economic analysis and modeling rather than simply projected from ex post data.

      Nevertheless, whether based on prior observations or on economic analysis, the return distribution is a central tool for understanding the characteristics of an investment. The normal distribution is the starting point for most statistical applications in investments.

      4.1.2 The Normal Distribution

      The normal distribution is the familiar bell-shaped distribution, also known as the Gaussian distribution. The normal distribution is symmetric, meaning that the left and right sides are mirror images of each other. Also, the normal distribution clusters or peaks near the center, with decreasing probabilities of extreme events.

      Why is the normal distribution so central to statistical analysis in general and the analysis of investment returns in particular? One reason is empirical: The normal distribution tends to approximate many distributions observed in nature or generated as the result of human actions and interactions, including financial return distributions. Another reason is theoretical: The more a variable's change results from the summation of a large number of independent causes, the more that variable tends to behave like a normally distributed variable. Thus, the more competitively traded an asset's price is, the more we would expect that the price change over a small unit of time would be the result of hundreds or thousands of independent financial events and/or trading decisions. Therefore, the probability distribution of the resulting price change should resemble the normal distribution. The formal statistical explanation for the idea that a variable will tend toward a normal distribution as the number of independent influences becomes larger is known as the central limit theorem. Practically speaking, the normal distribution is relatively easy to use, which may explain some of its popularity.

      4.1.3 Log Returns and the Lognormal Distribution

      For simplicity, funds often report returns based on discrete compounding. However, log returns offer a distinct advantage, especially for modeling a return probability distribution. In a nutshell, the use of log returns allows for the modeling of different time intervals in a manner that is simple and internally consistent. Specifically, if daily log returns are normally distributed and independent through time, then the log returns of other time intervals, such as months and years, will also be normally distributed. The same cannot be said of simple returns. Let's take a closer look at why log returns have this property.

      The normal distribution replicates when variables are added but not when they are multiplied. This means that if two variables, x and y, are normally distributed, then the sum of the two variables, x + y, will also be normally distributed. But because the normal distribution does not replicate multiplicatively, x × y would not be normally distributed. Aggregation of discretely compounded returns is multiplicative. Thus, if R1, R2, and R3 represent the returns for months 1, 2, and 3 using discrete compounding, then the product [(1 + R1)(1 + R2)(1 + R3)] − 1 represents the return for the calendar quarter that contains the three months. If the monthly returns are normally distributed, then the quarterly return is not normally distributed, and vice versa, since the normal distribution does not replicate multiplicatively. Therefore, modeling the distribution of discretely compounded returns as being normally distributed over a particular time interval (e.g., monthly) technically means


Скачать книгу