.
Читать онлайн книгу.make this more concrete, think of how FOSS production relates to (1) mainstream and proprietary software production and (2) market pressures. FOSS is often understood as having a dichotomous relationship with proprietary software, for example Linux vs. Apple/Microsoft. In this sense Linux distributions like Debian and Ubuntu seek to distinguish themselves as autonomous actors in comparison to the heteronomous positions of large companies who are more likely to bow to market demands and political restrictions. They do this not just through the fact that they make their source code freely available, but also by enacting sets of values that they perceive to be lacking in mainstream commercial development, such as a commitment to open technological standards, improving access to computing, or allocating resources to projects or solutions they deem technically superior. They thus actively pursue autonomy as they perceive it. They oppose market pressures in different ways, not just through their opposition to intellectual property regimes but also to certain judgments of quality (e.g., Debian prides itself on being an operating system geared towards other software developers). Importantly, Bourdieu consciously uses the term “semi‐autonomy”: pressures from the market, state, and other fields are always present, but it is a matter of degree.
Using field theory, we can thus consider how a peer production project enacts a form of relative autonomy in relation to other actors in a field of production – open source vs. proprietary software companies, Wikipedia vs. commercial reference media, etc. Again, making the connection to older cultural fields, think of how the example of the Debian Linux distribution is similar to how a reputable newspaper or weekly political magazine distinguishes itself from more commercial or mainstream actors. Where Debian’s developers seek to maintain a commitment to technical elegance and to serving other developers in ways that distinguish their product from more proprietary or mass‐market operating systems, quality news organizations similarly seek to uphold their own field‐specific definitions of quality and distinguish themselves from popular journalism such as tabloid newspapers – such journalism might offer a less entertaining, denser product that is appreciated by a smaller audience, while their peers in tabloid news are more likely to adjust content to expectations of what the audience would like to read and subject themselves to criticisms of superficiality, sensationalism, and the like. At the same time, note that in the context of “semi‐autonomy” this is a matter of degree, and it hardly means that quality newspapers ignore their audience or advertising revenue, or that Debian software developers never accommodate the needs of proprietary applications. Likewise, this does not mean that tabloid journalists feel their work is not valuable, as they for example can point out that they engage more readers (see e.g. Deuze, 2005a). What it does mean is that actors who take up an autonomous position within a field will demonstrate a commitment to certain shared values and seek to uphold what they perceive as a more “pure” or “quality” form of cultural production.
Autonomy is closely tied to another key concept in Bourdieu’s field theory, namely symbolic capital. Symbolic capital can be thought of as a field‐specific form of reputation, and it is gained informally through recognition from peers and critics and formally through prestigious rewards (e.g., particular roles, jobs, awards, mentions in the trade press, etc.). Think of this, again, in the context of journalism: there is symbolic capital in writing for The New York Times, in receiving a Pulitzer prize, when peers cite your work in other journalistic venues, and so on. Symbolic capital is related to autonomy such that it is often at odds with economic capital. As many of us will recognize from the experience of watching a favorite music artist “sell out,” there is a reputational cost that may come with commercial success. Gaining symbolic capital increases one’s status in a particular field, and combines with other forms of capital (economic, cultural, and social) to generate hierarchies.
Much of the interest around peer production is focused on the “puzzle” of individuals collectively organizing their labor largely independent of firms (e.g., managers with the authority to hire and fire) and price‐based mechanisms, such as wages (Benkler, 2002). Bourdieu would likely argue that such non‐market based production has long existed in semi‐autonomous fields, and is only a puzzle because we remain blind to (1) the ways in which all cultural production is distributed and (2) the different forms of capital that exist beyond economic capital. Wikipedia, open source, and other forms of peer production are certainly new, but they also extend the logics of existing cultural fields.
If autonomy is defined as the capacity to act in ways that resist pressures from other fields, then what comes in the place of that pressure? What guides action within, say, the art world, if it is not the market, state, or other external power? Field theory assumes that the competition for symbolic capital is what motivates actors, and that this circulation of symbolic capital is in turn geared toward reinforcing core values and principles that, while not immutable, are at the heart of what is considered good practice or purpose within a field, and thus what must be protected from outside influence. These values can be as diverse as creative expression and aesthetic innovation (summarized as “art for art’s sake”) in the art world (Bourdieu, 1993) to serving the public interest in the field of journalism (Benson & Neveu, 2005; Deuze, 2005b).
Here, too, we can look to Wikipedia and open source software to see how this interplay of autonomy, values, and symbolic capital is present in peer production projects. For Wikipedia, notions of universal access and the unfettered pursuit of knowledge would be considered important shared values, and participants are recognized (and recognize each other) for their efforts in support of them. Among Wikipedia participants, symbolic capital is gained through “barn stars” and other forms of peer recognition, as well as through appointments to positions within Wikipedia’s bureaucratic hierarchy. Less formally, symbolic capital is gained by being a visible contributor to the overall project, whether through providing expertise for certain topics, productively engaging in backend discussion, building software tools to help editors work more efficiently, and so on. As participants gain symbolic capital, this esteem will give them a better chance of mobilizing peers when it comes to conflicts and key decisions relating to the project.
The values enacted by Wikipedia and open source software communities are notable for how they are related to process as much as end product. As Kelty (2008) argues, open source software communities can be understood as “recursive publics.” That is, the identity of these communities are built on a kind of meta‐level: if publics normally form around a shared interest (e.g., fans of the same musician or citizens engaging with a particular political issue), what is remarkable in the geek cultures of Wikipedia and open source software production is that identity is largely tied to values and practices related to how communication takes place (including in the technical sense of which tools are used), rather than the content of that communication. As Kelty writes, such publics are “vitally concerned with the material and practical maintenance and modification of the technical, legal, practical, and conceptual means of [their] own existence” (2008, p. 3). For example, what ties the identity of Wikipedians together is less the content of the encyclopedia, and more their shared commitment to their desire for open and transparent processes for writing articles and settling disputes.
Another point that may be extrapolated from the discussion of autonomy above is that the most famous peer production projects can be seen in the context of what Kelty calls geeks’ “reformist” identity. Kelty notes that these communities of software makers often narrate their own identities through implicit and explicit analogies to the Protestant Reformation, where the control of technology and media (religion) is taken away from corporations (the Church) and restored to its original purpose by true believers (the geeks). For Kelty, the implicit analogy can be sensed in how notions of good and evil are deployed by these communities. For example, an open source software producer may find it “evil” when a large software company ignores an open standard and instead pushes a proprietary one onto its users. Likewise, a Wikipedian dedicated to the universal access of information may find it “evil” for companies to copyright or otherwise prevent access to useful knowledge, such as when academic publishers put scholarship behind expensive paywalls. In this way, we can see Wikipedia and open source as relatively autonomous forms of technical and media production, and that this position is narrated and articulated through stories (or “myths”) that echo the story structure of the Reformation (and these stories may be reproduced socially).
In