The Digital Economy. Tim Jordan

Читать онлайн книгу.

The Digital Economy - Tim Jordan


Скачать книгу
buyers is its search engine. In the period of Google’s development focused on here, two broad routes are offered. One is that when someone searches for a term related to a product being advertised, then the websites our advertiser has designated show up in the advertising sections of the Google page on which the search query is returned. The second is that Google facilitates ads appearing on other companies’ websites and, again, our advertiser can pay for their products and related sites to show up on sites other than Google’s.

      To appear on the search page is to directly draw on the magnet of Google search. Ads appearing here are marked out in slightly different colours and with words indicating that they are ads – ‘sponsored’ often appears – ensuring that they remain distinct from the search results. If our advertiser works for a business that sells package holidays, they may want their site to be advertised to anyone searching for terms like ‘Disney’, ‘beach’ and so on. To do this they have to decide what kinds of words a user might type into search that would indicate they might be interested in holiday products. Google runs an auction on keywords and advertisers bid according to how much they are willing to pay each time someone clicks on the advertisement. The way Google’s auction is set up guarantees that the winner only pays just above whatever the second highest bid was. Once the auction is won, the ads our advertiser wishes to be seen will appear on Google’s search page when the words are used in a search. If a user then clicks on the ad, the advertiser pays Google. There are complications to this simple scenario – such as Google rating good or bad ads, the standards ads must meet, and the information Google offers advertisers to improve their ads and so on – but the fundamentals are in this practice of buying words at auctions which result in ads being served to users of Google search (Turrow 2011: 67; Levy 2011: 87–93).

      The third set of intersecting activities, or third point of view, making up the economic practices of Google search are those of Google itself. These activities split between the structures set up by the company that allow it to offer services and mediate between search users and advertisers, and the implementation of those structures in the software/hardware that allows practices to be automated. This connection transformed Google and established one kind of digital economic practice as a money gusher, as noted earlier in the company’s turn from loss to profit once Adwords was implemented. To sustain this, Google’s economic practices have a dual character, with a never-ending process of improving search alongside never-ending developments in advertising.

      We have followed a single search from the point of view of the individual searcher, but from Google’s point of view things appear differently. Instead of the individual who searches, Google has to first see the collective and its social relations, which it can read to judge what search results to deliver. From this point of view, a search question is the last point of a search enquiry; it is what leads up to the delivery of certain results in a certain order that determines whether a search engine will be good or bad. This also highlights a recurrent frustration in trying to follow digital economic practices, as the algorithms and programs that fuel search engines are generally industry (or government) secrets. In the case of Google, however, the broad principles are known because its theoretical foundation, the PageRank algorithm, is publicly available (Page et al. 1999).

      To fully grasp the significance of this use of the World Wide Web we need to remember that what Google were (and are) reading through PageRank is a collectively created store of information to which anyone with access to the internet can add on topics of their choosing, including linking as website creators feel is appropriate. The WWW is created by following a set of formal standards that define how you have to form information and load it on a networked computer for it to be visible to other sites (as will be discussed further in Chapter 5). Once a website is visible other sites can link to that site just as anyone can link to their sites. The standards were released to be freely available and are maintained by a not-for-profit consortium. Much of the content that was created was done so freely by ordinary users with internet access and computing resources, though over time corporate and government sites run by paid employees have played a greater role. The WWW is then a collective creation formed of a series of groups that link to each other because they choose to do so in order to ensure that relevant information is connected and available. Although it was heavily commercialised once it became popular, the WWW preceded the birth of Google, and remains a space in which groups of people with similar interests can generate and share information resources (Berners-Lee 2000; Gillies and Cailliau 2000).

      PageRank was a means of reading these linked groups and their social relations. Once PageRank had read, for example, sites devoted to surfing it had evidence of the most important sites based on those who loved surfing and had created sites on the subject, including what those people thought were the most important sites and topics. This was the key work done in the initial Google search engine which can be drawn on when someone makes a surf-related search query. In this sense, any search query comes last in the practices of answering it, after the work has been done to read the relevant topics represented on the WWW.

      One of the best-known early additions to PageRank was the Random Surfer Model, which injected, as its name implies, randomness by assuming that at certain points anyone following


Скачать книгу