India. Craig Jeffrey

Читать онлайн книгу.

India - Craig Jeffrey


Скачать книгу
and thought to have been the outcome of the bank nationalization that took place in 1969, and of increasing numbers of bank branches, the result of the policy enforced by the Reserve Bank of India for banks to open up branches in areas previously poorly served by them. The increase in the savings rate was closely matched by increased investment rates; and Sen (2007) has shown that the increase in capital formation from the mid-1970s involved a rise in investment in equipment, as opposed to investment in construction, that had predominated hitherto. Cross-country research has shown this to be the form of investment that matters most for growth, and Sen argues, ‘the increase in private investment in equipment had a strong positive effect on growth, working its way through both capital accumulation and aggregate productivity growth’ (Kar and Sen 2016: 31, citing Sen 2007). He thinks that the new trend followed both from the financial deepening that had taken place, and from the decline in the relative price of machinery that had resulted from relaxation of import controls. The analysis still leaves open, however, the important question as to why private investment increased in the way it did in the 1980s – it doesn’t automatically follow from an increase in the savings rate. We return to this question below.

      SOURCE: Bosworth and Collins (2015, table 1) (these authors’ estimates, as described in their text)

      a Average change of 2011–12 and 2012–13

      There is a strong case for a more systematic approach to the distinguishing of growth episodes in India, one not driven by a particular hypothesis. Such an approach requires both ensuring that the structural breaks identified are statistically significant and that each of the episodes distinguished has ‘a single underlying medium-term growth rate’, over a substantial period (so as to distinguish them from business cycle fluctuations and short-term shocks). This is the analytical procedure that Kar and Sen have followed (2016: 5), and it leads them to identify three distinct episodes: 1950–92, 1993–2001 and 2002–10, with a possible fourth after 2010. They do recognize, however, a ‘nascent recovery’ in the 1980s – the period of the distinct break in India’s history of growth that we and Joshi and many others have identified – and though the acceleration in that period was not sufficient to satisfy their conditions for a structural break, Sen (2014) detected a shift from the trend line of growth in the late 1970s. There is also the view – expressed, for instance, by Joshi (2017), in line with Kar and Sen’s analysis – that there was a distinct period of particularly high growth in the 2000s, from 2002–3 to the end of the decade, with a fall thereafter. There appear to be substantial grounds, therefore, for thinking in terms of the three growth episodes, with the possible fourth after 2010, that Kar and Sen distinguish, or even of five episodes, if we pick out as distinct the period from around 1980 to 1992. We now consider each of these episodes, in turn, arguments about what was going on in each of them, the settlements between political and economic elites that they reflect, and their implications for changes in those settlements.

      SOURCES: Panagariya (2008); Kohli (2006a, 2006b)

      The story of India’s economic growth in the long period of the political dominance of the Congress Party, from the foundations of the republic through to 1989 – only briefly interrupted, by the Janata government that ruled from April 1977 to the beginning of 1980, following Mrs Gandhi’s Emergency of 1975–77, when democracy was suspended – is, therefore, often represented as one of failure. According to Kar and Sen, ‘For most of this period, the Indian economy experienced a prolonged


Скачать книгу